Sound advice

Tales from the homeworld

My current feeds

Fri, 2006-Mar-17

Emergent Efficient Software

This bugzilla comment came across my desk this morning:

If there are any developers out there interested in implementing this functionality (to be contributed back to Mozilla, if it will be accepted) under contract, please contact me off-bug, as my company is interested in sponsoring this work.

The comment applies to a mozilla enhancement request for SRV record support. SRV records are part of the DNS system, and would allow one level of server load balancing to be performed by client machines on the internet of today. Unfortunately, HTTP is a protocol that has not wholeheartedly embraced the approach as yet. What I think is interesting, however, is that there are customers who find bugs and want to throw money at them.

The extent to which this is true will be a major factor in the success of Efficient Software. This particular individual would like to develop a 1:1 releationship with a developer who can do the work and submit it back to the project codebase. I wonder how open they would be to sharing the burden and rewards.

This is the kind of bug that seems likely to attract most intrest for the Efficient Software initiative. It has gone a long time without a resolution. There is a subset of the community with strong views about whether or not it should be fixed. There seems to be some general consensus that it should be fixed, but for the project team for whatever reason it is currently not a priority.

It is unclear whether putting money into the equation would make this bug a priority for the core team, or whether they would prefer to stick to more release-critical objectives. There may be a class of developer who is more occasional that could take on the unit of work and may have an improved incentive if money were supplied. That is how I see the initiative making its initial impact: By working at the periphery of projects. I don't see the project being a good selector of which bugs should recieve funds because, after all, if the cashed up core developers thought it was release critical they would already be working on it. No, it is the user base who should supply the funds and determine which bugs they should be directed to.

There are important issues of trust in any financial transaction. I think that an efficient approach can adress these issues. The individual who commented on the SRV record bug is willing to contract someone to do the work, but whom? How do they know whether the contractor can be trusted or not? The investor needs confidence that their funds will not be exhausted if they are supplied towards work that is not completed by the original contractor. Efficient software does this by not paying out the responsible party (the developer or the project) until the bug is actually resolved. Likewise, the contractor must know their money is secure. Efficient Software achieves this by requiring investment is supplied up-front into effectively an escrow account while the work is done.

The biggest risk for an investor is that they will put their money towards a bug that is never resolved, despite the incentive they provide. A project may fork if funds are left sitting in the account. The investor's priorities may change. They may want that money put to a more productive use. I don't know of any way to mitigate that risk except to supply more and more incentive, or to first find a likely candidate to perform the implementation before actually putting funds into escrow. Perhaps the solution is to allow investors to withdraw funds assigned to a bug up until the bug is commenced. Once work is started, the money cannot be withdrawn. If the developer fails to deliver a resolution they may return the bug to an uncommenced state and investors can again withdraw funds to put to a more productive use.

The fact that the efficient software approach is an emergent phenomenon gives me increased confidence that it can be developed into workable process. In time, it may even become an important process to the open source software development world. Do you have comments or suggestions regarding an efficient approach to software? Blog, or join us on our mailing list.

Benjamin

Sun, 2006-Mar-12

Bounty Targeting

Bounties have been traditionally seen in open source as a way of brining new blood into a project, or increasing the pool of developer resources available to open source. Offering money for the production of a particular feature is intended to inspire people not involved with the project to come in, do a piece of work, then go back to their day to day lives. The existing developers may be too overworked to implement the feature themselves due to preexisting commitments. The item of work may even be designed to cross project boundaries and inspire cooperation at a level that did not exist before the bounty's effect was felt.

There are seveeral problems with this view of a bounty system, but perhaps the most important is one that Mary Gardiner identifies:

I mean, these things just seem like a potential minefield to me. And I don't mean legally, in the sense of people suing each other over bountified things that did or did not happen or bounties that did or did not get paid. I just mean in the sense of an enormous amount of sweat and blood spilled over the details of when the task is complete.

The point she makes is that it isn't possible to simply develop new feature x as a stand-alone piece of software and dump it into someone else's codebase. There is a great deal of bridge building that needs to happen on both the technical and social levels before a transfer of code is possible between a mercenary developer and an fortified project encampment.

These are the same kinds of issues a traditional closed software house has when they hire a contractor. Who is this contractor? What are their skills? Why are they being paid more than me? Will they incorporate into our corporate culture? Will their code incorporate into our codebase? Will they follow our development procedures and coding standards? There are plenty of ways to get each other off-side.

I consider it important to look for in-house talent. I don't think bounty systems should be geared towards the outside contractor, but instead to the core development team. I don't think bounty funds should be provided by the core development team to outsiders. Instead, I see bounties as a way for users of free software to contribute effectively to the core development team.

The Effient Software view of bounty collection and dispersion is that bounties are paid to developers who are already integrated on a social and techinical level with the core team. They may be full time or part time. They may work with other projects as well. This does not make them a mercenary. These are the people who don't come to the project just to do a single job. They watch the mailing lists. They spend appropriate time in irc channels and involved in other forms of instant communications for the sake of resolving technical issues. It is the core developer who should be rewarded for meeting the needs of the project's user base. It is the core developer who has the best chance of a successful development.

Finding the conclusion of the development should be straightforward and uncontraversial. It is as per project policy. The policy may be that an initial code drop is sufficient to collect a bounty. The policy may require a certain level of unit testing or review. It may require a certain level of user satisfaction. Because the developer is engaged in the policy process, the process is not a surprise or a minefield. Newer developers may be attracted to the project by successful funding of more established developers, and will have to break into the culture and policy... but that is to be expected when an outsider wants to become part of any core development group. The newcomer learns the policies over time, and the policies are as reasonable as the project needs them to be to both attract new blood and to fund the project as a whole. The interesting thing about open source is that if they get this balance wrong, it is likely they will be outcompeted by another group working on a fork of their software. The incentive is strong to get it right.

Money is a dangerous thing to throw into any organisation, and most open source projects get by without any dependable supply. There are real risks to changing your development model to one that involves an explicit money supply. I see rewards, however, and I see an industry that is ready to turn down this path. I think open source is the best-poised approach to take this path to its natural conclusion of efficient software production.

Benjamin

Sat, 2006-Mar-04

Free Software is not about Freedom of Choice

I was at HUMBUG last week, and was involved in a wide-ranging discussion. The topic of a particular closed-source software product came up, and a participant indicated that he maintained a windows desktop just to run the software. It was so good and integral to his work practices that he had a whole machine dedicated to it. He went on to criticise sectors of the open source community who tended to be irritated that closed source software was still in use. These are the sectors who have somewhat of a "with us" or "against us" view, and would prefer that closed source not be a part of anyone's lives. He asked (I think I'm getting the words right, here) After all, isn't free software about freedom of choice?.

I don't think it is.

Software alternatives are about freedom of choice. Whether the alternative is open source or closed source, the freedom of choice is not really affected. If I wrote a closed source alternative to Word, I would be providing freedom of choice to consumers. If I wrote an open source alternative to Word, I would be providing the same kind of freedom of choice. The difference is in the freedom of the customer once a transaction has been made. Open source software is primarily about post-choice customer freedom rather than freedom of choice, so it makes sense on at least one level for free software advocates to actively seek out unshackled alternatives to any closed source software they use from day to day.

In the software world we would traditionally see the freedoms of a consumer and the freedoms of a producer of software to be in conflict, however the foundation of open source development is to view the separation of consumer and producer as artificial. Freedoms given to the consumer are also given back to the producer, because the producer is also a consumer of this software. The barrier between consumer and producer exists naturally when only one entity is doing the producing. In that case the producer has automatic freedoms, and granting more to themselves has no meaning. However, consider the case of multiple producers. The freedoms granted to consumers are also granted to every producer when the production is shared between multiple entities. Open source produces a level playing field where entities that may compete in other areas can each limit the cost of this particular shared interest domain by working together.

When viewed from the angle of productivity improvement in a domain of shared interests, closed source alternatives can seem ugly and limiting. You will always know you are limited in closed source no matter how featureful a particular product is. You often can't make it better, and it would cost you a great deal to produce a competitive alternative as an individual. If competative alternatives exist you may be able to transition to one of the available alternative products, however you will still be in the same boat. You can't add a feature, and it only the threat you may change to another competitor that drives the supplier to use your license fee to produce software that suits you better. The competitors won't be sharing their code base with each other, so the overall productivity of the solution is less than the theoretical ideal. If the competitors joined forces they may be able to produce a more abundant feature set for a lower cost, however while they compete the customer pays for the competition. Which is worse? An unresponsive monopoly, or a costly war of features? Closed software represents a cost that the customer cannot easily reduce in an area that is different from their core competancies. It behaves like taxation from a supplier that does not need to outlay any more to continue reaping the benefits of its invesment, or a set of suppliers that duplicate efforts at the cost of the combined customer base. Open source may provide a third alternative: A cooperative of customers each working to build features they need themselves, and forking when their interests diverge.

People who are interested in open source are often also interested in open standards. Unlike open source, open standards do promote freedom of choice. Unlike open standards, open source does promote post-choice freedoms. Both have a tendancy to promote community building and shared understandings, and both are important to the health of the software industry moving forwards. The worst combination for overall productivity is and will continue to be a closed source product that uses closed data formats and interaction models.

Benjamin

Sat, 2006-Feb-11

Efficient Software at Humbug

We had a good preliminary scoping discussion today at HUMBUG. I caught the end of Pia Waugh's talk, and the linux.conf.au 2006 debreif lead by Clinton Roy. After dinner a few of us clustered around a chalk board at the front of the lecture theatre. A good canvassing of some of the direction issues was had, despite most of it being carried out before Anthony Towns returned from a separate dinner trip.

I was on the chalkboard, and wrote up the Efficent Software Initiative problem statement as follows (excuse my basic inkscape reproduction):

A person's time and their money are often in conflict when working with free software

Libre software is often written gratis, however those who write the software still need to live. They need to feed their families. In short, they need a day job. A lucky few are employed to write open source software for specific companies that use it. Many others are weekend soliders.

We are at a stage in the development of the software industry as a whole where it is usually necessary to be a full time software developer in order to be a particularly useful software developer. It takes a number of years of study and practical application to write good software, and we want our free software to be good. For those not employed to work on open source, their day job will likely include closed source software. Now, let's assume we "win". There isn't any appreciable amount of closed software development going on anymore. Do these guys lose their day jobs, or can they be employed to work on open source software in a new and different way? It is the function of the Efficient Software Initiative to build a base of discussion and experimentation to answer that question. We want to give as many people as possible the chance to work full time on free software, which means giving them an income.

The initial diagram became a little more complicated as we tried to model the software industry that supports open source developers today. We started by drawing links to that all-important money bubble. The goal was to describe where the money is coming from, including where a business that employs open source software develpers ultimately gets its money from. A simplified version of the diagram follows:

Paid open source development is mostly contingent on a genuinely separate business

If free software takes over we lose the ability to charge licence fees to support the developer's day job. I see the support-based business model for software development as weak, also. It may have conflicting goals to that of the production of good quality software with a balanced feature set. Real strength in an open source business model comes from being useful to other industries. That does not necessarily mean outside the world of computers. Google or Yahoo have established business models in the internet search industry, and serving their interests is a way of rooting the money supply available to open source without depending on closed software in the value chain. Other industries and established business models abound, including everything from avionics to resturants. To be productive, an open source industry has to appeal fairly directly to this wide audience. These industries can and should be engaged incrementally and won over with sound business logic.

So if we trace our connections back to the developer, we see two main paths still open for the raising of funds. We could try and get them employed directly by businesses that need software and want their particular interests represented in the development of a project going forwards. Alternatively, we could try and raise money over a wider base from the whole user community. This is a community of individuals and of companies who have an interest and an investment in your project's ongoing success. Your project represents a point at which their interests all overlap. The main things that matter on an encomic level in maintaining the community and successfully drawing contributions from the community are to match your project goals with the community interests and to ensure that individual contributions are returned in spades as a collectively built product.

This is an interesting and important facet to the bean counting motivation for open source in business. Businesses like to deal with the existing software industry. They pay a small fee, and in return they get to make use of the produce from hoards of programmers over several years (if not several decades). Open source makes it possible to do the same thing for business. Even though they contribute only a small amount individually, they each recieve the benefit of the total common contribution. They often don't need to work on a bug that affects them to see it fixed. The effort is often expended by someone else who felt the pain more stronly or immediately. Licences such as the GPL also provide some level of certainty to contributors that what they have collaboratively built won't be taken by any single contributor and turned back into a product that does not benefit them.

The difference between open and closed source approaches to this multiplicative return is that open source is more efficient. It stands to reason that when it is possible to fork a product, there is a lower cost of entry to the business than if you had to rewrite from scratch. For an example, just consider the person-years of effort that have been extended on the GNU Classpath, despite Sun having a perfectly good implementation in their back pocket the whole time. If the barrier to entry is lowered, competition or the potential for it increases. This should lead to a more productive and lower cost industry. The current industry forms monopolies wherever there is a closed file format or undocumented API. An industry remade as open source would see none of that, and the customers should benefit.

Benjamin

Thu, 2006-Feb-09

Patent and Copyright in and Efficent Software Industry

This is the first in a series of articles I may or may not get around to writing over the next week or so to clarify some ideas leading into the Efficient Software Initiative. Some of the ground in this article is covered also in Math You Can't Use, who's sixth chapter I read after drafting. I think this article is a little more focused on the core economic issues and has value standing on its own. Note that Math You Can't Use makes use of the terms "goods-oriented" and "labour-oriented". I use the terms "manufacturing industry" and "service industry" for analogous concepts. Disclaimer: I am a software developer, not an economist.

It is incorrect to say that software is just maths, and is therefore not patentable. Physics and engineering are just maths, so our total understanding of our physical environment is just maths. If that were sufficient justification to prohibit patent, all engineering design would be exempt from the system. We must instead look for an econmic justification for prohibition of patent on software, and I think such a justification can be made.

The patent and copyright systems attempt to solve the same base problem. If I invest a certain monetary value of time and skills into a product development it is important I can recoup my costs and ideally can make a profit. Because my initial investment excluded input from other parties, so should the benefits I reap. I deserve a limited time monopoly on what I produce.

The problem with this reasoning is that it essentially applies to a manufacturing industry. A manufacturing industry is one where an initial investment is made before and throughout a development cycle, before a later cycle allows me to recoup my costs and feed my family. Mass-market software has traditionally been a manufacturing industry, however this is changing. The software industry is remaking itself around services.

Services follow a different business model. Instead of having to recoup costs at a later stage of product development, services acquire funding "in-phase". Software developers will remember that the old ideal for software development was the waterfall model. Requirements definition was followed by design, and then by implementation. After implementation comes sale and the recouping of costs. We have been moving away from that model for many years. It patently does not work for most software devlopement. Instead, we began with spiral models and have ended up with agile or extreme methods. These approaches to software development dictate a cyclic model. You plan a little, you implement a little, you test a little, and you deploy a little. An important economic aspect of these models is the potential for in-phase recoup of costs.

The agile approach goes as far as saying that a customer representative is on your development team. They drive this week's development and have enough insight into the development as a whole to help make go/no-go decisions for the project. If funding should stop, that is ok. The customer will have selected their most important features for early implementation and will have discontinued the project only as diminishing returns make continuing uneconomic. Because the funding was in-phase, all costs have been covered for the developers. There is nothing that needs to be recouped after the implementation phase. The roles of customer and investor have merged.

So if software is a service rather than a manufacturing industry, if software development does not have to recoup its costs out of phase, then it stands to reason that patent and traditional copyright do not benefit the industry as a whole. The barrier to entry that both systems create to new entrants (particularly the patent system) is a deliberately anti-competative feature and an anti-productive one. They will have an overall negative economic effect when there is no corresponding productivity increase created by the out of phase recoup of costs. Given the software industry's growing importance to the world's economy, it stands to reason that both systems need to die for software. Software patents should be the first to go.

Patents and copyright do not make sense in a services industry. If I patent the ideas behind a dog-walking industry, customers cannot be benefited. Instead, I will be reducing the quality and scope of services available to them and increasing their costs. I should be putting my energies into running my service efficiently, and outsource that which is not my core competancy. If new ideas will make me more efficient I'll spend the research and development dollars to produce them, but the funding will come from the business I run and not from the sale of these ideas to other dog walkers. The same analogy applies to the software industry. If I patent the ideas behind internet search or behind the playing of video files, I am reducing the quality and scope of services available to computer users. I should focus on providing great search and video services to my users and use those dollars to fund any necessary research. If my service is providing software to make a particular business model more efficient, I should focus on meeting customer demand for efficiency improvements. I should not be trying to sell them a product. When the industry is built around in-phase cost structures the patent system only acts to prevent my competitors from matching my performance in ways that lock them out of the whole industry and provide an overall poorer marketplace for the services themselves. Economically speaking, it is the services that count. It isn't the paltry research industry sector.

Patents are intended for industries where it takes a number of years to develop a product and the costs must be recouped later. This works in drug industries. It may even work in research sectors of the computer industry. If I labour away at creating a new video codec system that greatly improves quality for the same computational and bandwidth requirements as convetional technology, I need a way to recoup my spent youth. If such an incentive is not given, the improvements may not be made. However, I would argue that the bulk of the industry will be services-based. Some segments will be hurt by the transition, but for the most part a greater level of innovation will be recorded rather than a lesser one. Segments based around services will work to fund other segments in order to improve their own services offering. This will occur naturally as required, and will also be in the form of in-phase funding.

The change is already beginning, but at the same time existing players in the sofware market are rallying to try and keep competition out. The efficiency of the software industry will suffer if they succeed, and thus the efficiency of the world economy will also suffer.

Benjamin

Sat, 2006-Jan-28

Launch of the Efficient Software Project Plan, and Call for Participation

Free Software is Efficient Software, but Efficient Software won't come into being overnight. The Efficient Software Initiative has hit another (small) milestone, in releasing its first project plan:

  1. Conceive of idea
  2. Promote idea via blogs and other viral media (we are here)
  3. Build a base of discussion between individuals to agree on the right models for putting money into open source, including solid discussions on whether it is necessary or even useful
  4. Build a base of three or more people across disciplines to begin developing concrete policy, business plans, and site mockups. Continue promoting and building awareness until at least one slashdot effect is noted.
  5. Use wider promotion to get feedback on initial discussions and established policies. Learn which parts are defensible and which are not. Adjust as required, and begin building a core implementation group. This group will have access to sufficient funds between them to make the business a reality, and will likely have strong overlap with earlier core team.
  6. Launch business based on developed plans

This plan is likely to require at least twelve months of concerted attention, and will likely strech over several years if successful. The ultimate goal is to build not only a business, but a business model that can be replicated into an industry. The goal is to fund open source development and directly demonstrate the cost differential to closed source software. If you have any comments or feedback on the plan, please let us know via the mailing list.

With it comes a call for participation on the project front page:

You can help us get off the ground!

Do you have a background in law?
Help us understand the Legal Implications of the Business
Do you have a background in business or accounting?
Help us understand the Profit Implications of the Business
Do you have a background in website design?
Help us develop possible website designs (this will help everyone stay grounded!)
Do you have a background in running large websites?
Help us understand how to set everything up
Do you have roots in open source communities?
Talk about Efficient Software! Get feedback! Bring people on board with us, and help us come on board with them

So, why should you get involved? Who am I, and why should you trust me to get a project like this off the ground? Well, I am not asking anyone to trust me at this stage. We are in the discussion stages only. The next stage is to develop a core group of people to push things forward. Perhaps that group will include you. If you really want to know about me, well... here I am:

I have lived in Brisbane, Queensland for most of my life now. I graduated from the University of Queensland with a computer science honours degree back in 1998. Since the time of my course I have been a involved in HUMBUG. My open source credentials are not strong. I have done a few bits here and there at the edges of various communities. I was involved with the sqlite community for a time and have a technical editor credit on the book of the same name. I have recently been involved with the microformats community, particularly with recent hAtom developments. I'm a RESTafarian. I have used debian linux as my sole desktop install for at least five years, and saw the a.out to ELF transition. I'm a gnome user and advocate. I'm something of a GPL biggot, or at least it is still my default license. I work in control systems, and have spent the last few years trying to "figure out" the web. I'm a protocols and bits and bytes kind of guy. I use the terms "open source" and "free software" interchangably. I'm afraid of license incompatability in the open source world leading to a freedom that is no larger than what we see in closed source software. I'm a father to be, with less than seven weeks to go until maybe I won't have much time to do anything anymore. I'm a full-time sofware developer who does a lot of work in C++. I work more hours at my job than I am contractually obliged to, so often don't have time for other things. I have a failed open source accounting package behind me, where I discovered for the first time that user interfaces are hard and boring and thankless things. That project came out of my involvement with gnucash, which I still think would be easier to replace than fix. I think python needs static checking because the most common bug in computer software is not the off-by-one error, but the simple typo. I haven't used ruby on rails because I think that any framework that requires I learn a whole new language needs a few years for the hype to cool down before it gets interesting. I render my blog statically using blosxom, partially because I didn't have the tools at hand for dynamic pages using my old hosting arrangements, but partially because I'm more comfortable authoring from behind my firewall and not allowing submissions from anywhere on the web. I used to be a late sleeper, but have taken the advice of Steve Pavlina and have now gotten up at 6am for the last six weeks straight. With all the extra time I still haven't mowed the lawn. I'm not perfect, and I certainly don't have all the skills required to create a new open source business model on my own. That is why I want this to be a community. I know how effective a community can be at reaching a common goal, and I think that the Efficient Software Initiative represents a goal that many can share.

So sign up for the mailing list. Get into some angry conversations about how open source doesn't need an income stream, or how selling maintenence is the perfect way to make money from open source software. I want to have the discussion about whether the kind of business Efficient Software is trying to build will create a new kind of free software market, or whether it just puts a middleman in the way of an already free market. Let's have the discussions and see where we end up. Efficient Software is something I can get excited about, and I hope it is something you'll be able to get a bit excited about, too.

Benjamin

Sat, 2006-Jan-14

The Efficient Software Mailing List

Subject: [es] Free Software is Efficient Software

The Efficient Software initiative is growing slowly, but surely. We now have a wiki <https://efficientsoftware.pbwiki.com/>, an irc channel (#efficientsoftware on irc.freenode.net), and this mailing list. The post address is efficientsoftware at rbach.priv.at, and archives can be found at <https://rbach.priv.at/Lists/Archive/efficientsoftware/>.

We are looking forward to making positive connections with software projects, as well as lawyers, businesspeople, accountants, web site maintainers, and many more. To make this thing a reality we need to form a diverse community with a broad skill set.

The thing that will bring us all together is a desire for more efficient software production and maintanence. We can undercut the current players in the industry, and make a profit doing it. We can turn the weekend free software soldiers into a lean regular army with full time pay. We can match customer needs and pain to a speedy resolution. These are the goals of the Efficient Software Initiative.

Welcome to the community!

To join the mailing list, see the EfficientSoftware Info Page. A big thankyou goes out to Robert Bachmann for offering to host the list.

Benjamin

Wed, 2006-Jan-04

Efficient Software FAQ

Efficient Software has launched its FAQ, currently still on the main page. From the wiki:

Why start this initiative?

Too much money is being funnelled into a wasteful closed source software industry. Initially it is investors money, but then customers pay and pay. Profits to major software companies are uncompetatively high compared to other industries. We want to funnel money away from the wasteful industry and towards a more productive system of software development. Free software can be developed, forked, changed, and distributed without waiting on unresponsive vendors. Free software is open to levels of competition that cannot be matched by the closed source world. Free software contributors don't have to be on any payroll in order to fix the problems they care about. Free software does not maintain the artificial divide between customers and investors. The people who contribute to the development of a free software project are its customers, and all customers benefit when bugs are fixed or enhacements are carried out.

What do projects have to gain?

Our goal is to increase the money supply to projects. Money is not a necessary or sufficient factor in developing free software, but it cannot hurt. Projects often accept donations from users, but it is unclear how much users should give or what their motiviations are. Efficient Software aims to tie a contribution to services rendered. Whether the services are rendered immediately or a year from now is inconsequential. Efficient Software maintains a money supply that can be tapped by projects when they fix the nominated bugs.

Won't this drive the wrong bugs to be fixed?

Projects will nominate which state a bug has to be in for Efficient Software to accept payment. Bugs whose fix would contradict project goals should never be put into eligable states and will never recieve contributions. One way of thinking about the money involved is as bugzilla votes. The difference is that modern world currencies tend to have low inflation rates and limited supply. There is evidence across a number of fields that when people commit money to a goal they tend to make decisions more carefully, even if the amount is small. If your project's money supply has a wide base, the dollar value next to each bug should be a reasonble estimate of the value to users in getting it fixed. This information system alone could be worth your while becoming involved.

What should projects do with the money?

Efficient Software was conceived around the idea that projects would pay developers for the fixes they contribute through a merit-based mechanism. We have some thoughts about how this could work in practice, but we will need to develop them over time. In the end, projects are required to make their own "opt in" decision with Efficient Software and their own decision about how to distribute the money. This policy will be made available to contributors in case it may affect their investment decisions.

What if a project marks bugs verified just to get a payout?

Projects are free to mark bugs verfied under their own policy guidelines. We do not get involved, except to publish those guidelines to investors alongside other policies. However, beware that any investor who has contributed any amount towards a bug will have their say on whether they believe the resolution was in the overall sense positive, netural, or negative. Cumulative scores will be available to potential investors in case this may affect their investment decision.

Benamin

Mon, 2006-Jan-02

The Efficient Software Initiative

The Efficient Software wiki has been launched. From the wiki:

This wiki is designed to concentrate efforts to create a new software industry. It is an industry that does not rely on delivering parallel services in order to fund software development or on the payment of license fees, but instead yields return as software is developed. It leverages the ability of a project's own bug database to bring customer and developer together. Efficient Software is intended to become a business that helps put money into the model. Its business model will be developed in the open and will be free for anyone to adopt. The product is more important than any one implementation of the business model. Cooperation is good, but the threat of competition is healthy too.

The fundamental goal of the Efficient Software initiative is to increase the money available to free software projects and free software developers. Contributors currently make donations to software projects, but it is unclear how much they should give and what their motivation is beyond "these are nice guys, I like them". Efficient Software is designed to create a market in which customers and projects can participate to meet customer needs and project needs.

Have at it!

Also, I would love to hear from anyone who is prepared to host a mailing list for the initiative.

Update: The wiki now has edit capability, and there is an irc channel. Join #efficientsoftware on irc.freenode.net.

Benjamin

Sat, 2005-Dec-31

Paid Free Software

hAtom is currently stalled, awaiting a meeting of minds on the subject of css class names. I have been using the progress of hAtom and the related hAtom2Atom.xsl (Luke's repo, Robert's repo) to soak up excess energy over the first two weeks of my three week holiday. With that on hold I have energy to burn on two further projects. One is my old attempt at building a home accounting package. The other is trying to reason out a business model for paid free software.

Free Software is Efficient Software

Free software is a movement where the users of a piece of software are also its contributors. Contributors are secure in knowing the benefits they provide for others by their contribution will flow back to them in the form of contributions from others. With a reciprocal license such as the GPL a contributor knows their code won't be built upon by their competitors in ways that give their competitors advantage against them.

If everyone contributes to the same baseline the community of contributors benefits. The interests of the majority of contributors are served the majority of the time. When the interests of the group diverge, forking appears. These forks are also produced efficiently by body of contributors who remain on each side of the forked divide. Noone has to start from scratch. Everyone still has access to the original code base. Patches can still be transferred between the forks in areas where common need is still felt. If the reasons for divergence disappear, the contributor pool can even fold back together and form a common base once again.

Free software is not just a hippy red socialist cult. It is a free market of excess developer hours. Developers contribute, and gain benefits for themselves and for others. Projects are run efficiently along lines contributors define either explicitly or implicitly. The fact that so much free software has been developed and used based primarily on the contribution of individuals' spare time is a testament to how much can be achived with so little input.

Contributors of Money

Contributions in the free software world are almost exclusively made in terms of working code, or theoretical groundings for working code. There are areas such as translation for internationalisation and web site design and maintenence that come into it as well... but this is primarily a market for excess skills that are not exhausted in the contributor's day job. I see free software's efficiency as a sign that it can and should displace closed software development models in a wide range of fields. One way in which this might be accelerated is if a greater excess of skills could be produced. Perhaps your favourite web server would get the feature you want it to have faster if you paid to give a software developer an extra few hours off their day job.

There are reasons to be wary of accepting money for free software, but I think we can work around them. Full time paid staff on a free software development can gratis developers away, so we should pay our developers in proportion to the needs of money contributors that they meet. Boiled down to the essence of things, a money contributor should pledge to and pay the developer who fixes the bugs this contributor wants fixed. That's capitalism at work!

Running a Macro-money system (the business model)

In practice, the issue of resolving which individual should be paid what amount is more complex than matching a contributor to a developer. Perhaps the reviewer or the applier of the patch should get a slice. Perhaps the project itself should, or the verifier of the bug. I delved into some of the issues invovled in my earlier article, "Open Source Capitalism". I think there is a business to be made here, but it isn't going to be done by making decisions at this level. This is a project decision that should be made by projects. The business model at our global level is simple:

  1. Set up an eBay-style website
  2. Allow free software projects to sign on to be part of it (sign some up before your launch!)
  3. Allow followers of the registered projects to identify bugs, and attach money to them
  4. Monitor the bug tracking systems of each project, and pay the project out when the bug is verified

Two sources of income are available, percentages and earned interest. It seems reasonable to take a small cut of any money transferred through the site to cover expenses. Requiring money to be paid up front by contributors has several advantages, including the project doesn't achieve its goal only to find no reward waiting for it. The benefit to us, however, is the income stream that can be derived through interest earnt on unpaid contributions. Depending on the average hold time of a contributed dollar this could account for a reasonable portion of costs, and if excessive might have to be paid back in part to projects. If the business model is workable at all, keeping costs low from the outset will stave off competition and build project and contributor loyalty.

Projects define policy as to who (if anyone) money acquired in this way is distributed to. Projects also define policy on which bugs pledges can be placed upon (typically, only accepted bugs would be allowed), and when a bug is considered "verified". Policies must be lodged with the website and available for contributor perusal before any contributions are made. Contributors who feel their bugs have been resolved well can leave positive feedback. Contributors who feel their bugs have been resolved poorly or not resolved can leave negative feedback. These ratings are designed to ensure projects provide clear policy and stick to it, however all contributions are non-refundable barring special circumstances.

I don't know the legal status of all of this, particularly the tax implications or export control implications of dealing with various countries around the globe. Expert advice would certainly be required and money invested up front. Community outrage at the suggestion would also be a bad thing. Discussions and negotitions should occur early and the project probably can't proceed without gnome, kde, and mozilla all signed up before you get into it. Another angle of attack would be to sign up sourceforge, however they may see the system as a competitor of sorts to their paypal donations revenue stream. If you were to sign them up I think payments to sf projects would have to go via the sf paypal.

Conclusion

Consider this an open source idea. I would love to be involved in making something like this a reality, but I don't have the resources to do it myself. In fact, I don't necessarily bring any useful expertise or contacts to the table. Nevertheless, if you are in a position to make something like this happen I would like to hear about it. I might want to buy a share, if nothing else. Dear Lazyweb: Does anyone have a wiki space that could be used to develop this concept?

Benjamin

Mon, 2005-Oct-31

Open Source Capitalism, or "How to run your project as a business"

I wrote recently about the AJ Market, which allows people or organisations with a few dollars to spare to influence the focus of AJ's contribution to open source software development. If I contradict myself this time around please forgive me. I was running a little low on the sleep tank during my first attempt at a brain dump on the subject. This time around I'll try to stick to a few fundamentals.

Who writes the source?

If an open source software developer is to make money writing open source, he or she must be paid up front rather than making up the up front costs in license fees. There are different motiviations for funding open source. The contributor may be able to make direct use of the software produced. They may feel they can make money out of complimentary products such as services. They may be trying to favour curry with individuals in the software's target audience, leading to a return of good faith. The contributor may or may not be the same person as the developer. Traditionally the two have consistently been the same person. Developers wrote software to "scratch an itch" that affected them personally. This is a great model of software development where the software's users are the people most actively involved in driving the product as a whole. I see the possibility of opening up this market to also include people who can't scratch their itch directly but have the money to pay someone to do it.

The choice of license

Firstly, I think it is important to have a license that promotes trust in the community of users. My experience is that the GPL does this effectively in many cases by guaranteeing contributions are not unfairly leveraged by non-contributors. Eric Raymond chants that the GPL is no longer necessary because business sees open source as the most productive way forward and that businesses who fail to see this will fail to prosper. I disagree on the basis that through all of nature there are always some cheats. What works on the grand economic scale doesn't always make immediate business sense. The search for short term gain can wipe out trust and cooperation too quickly to give up on the protections that the GPL provides. When the global community of nation states no longer needs treaties to prevent or limit the use of tarriffs I'll start to look again at whether the GPL is required.

Voting with your wallets

My view of an economically vibrant project starts with Bugzilla. I intuitively like the concept of a bounty system in free software and think it ties in nicely with eXtreme Programming (XP) concepts. When you provide bounties for new work you should increase the supply of developers willing to do the work associated with the bug. When you allow the contribution of bounties to be performed by the broader user base you may align the supply of software development hours to the needs of the customer base. Bugzilla already has a concept of voting where registered users indicate bugs they really care about by incrementing a counter. If that counter were powered by dollars rather than clicks the figure may be both a more accurate statement of the desirability of a fix and a more motivating incentive for developers to contribute.

The tie in to me with XP is in breaking down the barrier between developer and customer. As I mentioned earlier, they are often already the same people in open source. An open flow of ideas of what work is most important and what the work's success criteria are is proving important in software development generally. In XP a customer representative is available at all times for developers to speak to. In open source, bugzilla is an open channel for discussion outside regular mailing lists. Adding money to the process may be a natural evolution of the bug database's role.

A question of scale

As I mentioned in my earlier article, the biggest problem in setting up a marketplace is ensuring that there is enough money floating around to provide meaningful signals. If a software developer can't make a living wage working on a reasonable number of projects this form of monetary open source is never going to really work. Open source also has a way of reducing duplication that might otherwise occur in proprietary software, so there is potentially far less work out there for software developers in a completely free software market. Whether it could really work or not is still a hypothetical question and starting work now on systems that support the model may still be exiting enough to produce reasonable information. Even if this model could only pay for one day a week of full-time software development it would be a massive achievement.

Governance and Process

If your project is a business you can pretty much run it any way you choose, but the data you collect and transmit through a closed system will be of lower quality than that of a free market. To run your project as a market I think you need a significant degree of transparancy to your process. I suggest having open books in your accounting system. When someone contributes to the resolution of a bug it should be recorded as money transferred from a bug-specific liability account to your cash at bank account. When the conditions for payout are met money should be tranferred from a developer-specific payable account back to the bug. Finally payment should be made from the cash at bank account to the payable account to close the loop. If the project has costs or is intended to run at a profit some percentage of the original transfer should be transferred from an appropriate income account rather than being transferred wholely from the liability. This approach clearly tracks the amount invested by users in each bug and transparently indicates the amounts being payed to each developer. I suggest that while contributions may be anonymous that developer payments should be clealy auditable.

Estimates and Bug Lifecycle

I'm going back on my previous suggestion to provide work estimates on each bug. I'm now suggesting that the amount of interest in supply be the main feedback mechanism for users who want to know how much a bug resolution is worth. More factors than that simply of money contribute to the amount of supply available for fixing a bug. There is the complexity of the code that is needed to work with to consider. There is the fun factor, as well as the necessity to interface to other groups and spend additional time. I would also suggest that different phases in a bug's lifecycle may be worth contributing to explicitly. If a bug is in the NEW state then money may be made available to investigate and specify the success criteria of later stages. Contributions may be separate for the development phase and a separate review phase. Alternatively, fixed percentages may be supplied to allow different people to become involved during different stages.

Bug Assignment Stability

Stablility of bug assignments is important as soon as money comes into the equation. There's no point in having all developers working individually towards the bug with the biggest payoff, only to find the bug is already fixed and payed out when they go to commit. Likewise, showing favouratism in assigning high value bugs the the same people every time could be deadly to project morale. I would take another leaf out of the eXtreme Programming book and suggest that leases be placed on bug assignments. The developer willing to put in the shortest lease time should win a lease bidding war. Once the lease is won the bug is left with them for that period. If they take longer then reassignment may occur.

Benjamin

Sat, 2005-Oct-22

Selling developer hours (generalising the AJ market)

Anthony Towns updates us on the status of the AJ market. He's a free software developer who is heavily involved in the Debian project.

Putting money in the market

I believe Anthony is hoping to do a number things with this market. Benefits that he might be able to achieve include:

These are all benefits that putting money and an economy into the system should be a good means of achieving. You want a new feature but can't do it yourself? Put your money where your mouth is and pay the man who can. A market that uses a low-inflation commodity to send signals between buyer and seller should provide accurate information about what most needs achieving. In a free software world commodities of money and developer time are both low inflation so probably both have a role to play.

Possible problems with AJ's market

Such an economy does need to be of sufficient scale to keep noise low. At the dollar figures AJ has reeled in so far it is an even bet whether the information he is recieving about customer demands is representative of his userbase or not. He may also not sending effective signals back to buyers about what is possible given the time available. His market information bulletin doesn't indicate how much he expects to be paid for any of the items in his todo list. He doesn't quote hours estimates and the bids are not for hours but features of possibly irregular size. Without a mechanism where AJ is able to say "I'm not willing to do this work for less than..." the market is only a one-way information system. These problems may be shaken out with time or prove irrelevant as obviously this market is very new indeed.

I wish, I wish

I've occasionally dreamed about a market like this myself. A nobody in the free software movement like myself would probably not get very far marketing in this way, at least initially. That has put me off investing any significant time in a model. I've tended to dislike the service-orientated redhat or mysql business models. I think these approaches encourage paid developers to think in terms of the services they are going to provide rather than in terms of the quality of the software. This could actively work against software quality by encouraging turnkey "just works" features to be excluded as reducing the value of services that might otherwise be provided. It may be better to use business models that directly encourage end user solutions that are of the highest quality necessary to do the job.

Problems with the proprietary approach

Proprietary software development is based around the production of a feature set that can sold over and over again. In the case of companies like microsoft this can lead to huge profit margins, which equate to inefficiency in the economy as a whole. If features have already been developed then making businesses pay for them over and over again is counter-productive. The amount that the business can spend on its own needs is reduced by the paying of licence fees while the software company itself is not solving new problems for the business. An efficient model would see the software company make a fair profit on the costs to produce features for other businesses while retaining the incentive to produce new features and further improve the productivity of their customers. Software companys that aren't producing more and better efficiency improvements for their customers should wither and die.

Problems with the free approach

In any free model you either need to get the money to produce features up front or you need to make the money back on services. As I mentioned earlier I'm not a fan of the services avenue, although I admit this can be a handy revenue stream. AJ's market attempts to make the money up front because once the work is done and is freely distributed there isn't going to be any more money coming in for that feature or efficiency improvement. Proprietary companies can afford to take a loss during development and make the money up later in sales. Free developers must be paid in advance.

As a free developer you really have two choices:

  1. You team up with an entity with deep pockets that wants your software
  2. You provide a means for collective entities with deep pockets to form

We see the first choice at work in services companies. They are willing to pay developers so that they can earn dollars providing services and addons to the software developed. The problem dealing with an entity of this type is that greed will eventually change your relationship. The company will want to see something from the development that its competitors don't have. This desire may conflict with a free software sensibility. It may only be "we want to have this for six months before everyone else". That's how copyright and patents work, of course. From experience with those two vehicles we know that companies will inevitably want longer and longer periods attached. It may come in the form of "we want this proprietary addon". The only counters to these forms of greed would be outrage in the customer community who really don't want the lock-in.

The second approach is that of AJ's market. Try to attract ad hoc collectives who want a feature to supply small contributions to the goal. To get as many people together as a proprietary company does with its license fee model may be a difficult feat, but you know that you're working towards real customer needs when a large number are willing to supply even small amounts.

The role of eXtreme Programming

Earlier in this article I critisized AJ for not supplying estimates for work and thus not providing adequate feedback to buyers in his economy. I've actually always seen this kind of market through the XP model and viewed it alongside the bounty system sometimes seen in free softare. The basic framework would consist of the following stages:

  1. Define a set of concrete, testable goals
  2. Allow bidding for a concrete non-inflationary commodity towards those goals
  3. Work for the highest bidder according to the amount of commodity bought
  4. Allow goals to be changed and rebid

This approach would accomodate two-way feedback between buyer and seller, including allowance for goal correction should the costs begin to outweigh the benefits of a particular unit of work. I propose the following implementations of each stage:

  1. Definition of testable goals
    Buyers should be able to submit goals to the seller. Seller should make appropriate adjustments to keep scope within a basic regular time period, such as splitting up the work into smaller units. Sellers should ignore or negotiate changes to goals that fall outside the basic project charter. Sellers may also propose and lobby for their own changes and may submit free hours towards goals they are passionate about.
  2. Bidding

    I think AJ has the basic bidding structure right. A bid is an actual payment of dollars rather than a promise of dollars. An alternative model would be to do an eBay-style bidding and invoicing separation where only the work with the highest return would be invoiced. Due the the nature of this work where weeks may pass between the first pledge of money for a particular bug and the actioning of work associated with the bug an invoicing system is probably too complex with the additional complication of having to price in non-payment.

    I think that bidding should be in the form of dollars for hours. Both are non-inflatable commodities and a fair average price should be able to be determined over the longer term. It should be possible to compare the hourly rate over a long period of time for trends and it should be possible for buyers to see what other people think an hour of your time is worth. Buyers may also submit code they hope will reduce or eliminate the effort required to fulfil their chosen goals.

    In my view, the best way to achieve a dollars for hours bidding model is to associate an estimate with each bug. Buyers make payments indicating their preferred bug. The payment total is divided by the estimate to produce an hourly rate. The seller works on the bug with the highest available hourly rate.

    The problem with bidding dollars for hours is how to handle inaccurate estimation. You could spend the estimated hours, pocket the money, and update the estimate for the bug. That might strain relations with your userbase and probably requires refunds for bugs that take less than the allotted time to resolve. Another approach would be for the seller to wear the risk of inaccurate estimates by always completing the work regardless of budget overrun. This would encourage the seller to underpromise, which is usually a good thing for a seller to do.

  3. Working
    There should be clear targets for time worked and the tests for completion should be defined by buyers as part of the goal definition. These should be prioritised so that the most important tests are met early. Bidders should be able to be tracked and contacted during the purchased time for clarification to ensure that the most applicable work is produced.
  4. Rebidding
    Goal changes should be made as necessary with the winning bidders for your time. Once the won hours have been expended buyers may choose to bid for more hours towards their goal or may abandon the goal as uneconomic.

Conclusion

Maybe someone can make use of these ideas. Maybe one day I'll be able to make use of the myself :) In the end software freedom should act as a contract to ensure successful bidders don't get a leg up on each other and that all market forces are openly played out. I hope that great free software may come out of a collective monetary process in the future. At present we have a system based on bidders paying with their own hours, and that's great... however it would be nice to see people with money be able to play the game as well and most importantly it would be nice to see free software being able to be created professionally without the need for paid services to fund the professionals

Benjamin